|
Despite the fact that Indian
Agriculture has made rapid strides in
increasing its production of wheat,
rice, cotton, sugar cane, fruits,
vegetables and milk productivity of
crops per hectare and milk per
lactation has been low as compared to
other countries as well as in the
world [Table No.1]. While India has a
very large net work of rural branches
of Commercial, Cooperatives and
regional rural banks impact of credit
on the productivity of crops and
livestock in particular has been
constrained due to several risk
factors and faulty credit policy. It
is against this background an attempt
is made here to appreciate different
types of risk factors on one hand and
need for efficient management of risks
on the other.
Dr. Amrit
Patel holds a doctoral
degree in Rural Studies and
Masters in Agricultural Science.
He has extensive research and
teaching experience with Gujarat
Agricultural University and
College of Agricultural Banking
of Reserve Bank of India. He has
extensive rural banking and
micro-credit experience with 25
years with the Bank of Baroda
and 10 years as consultant for
the World Bank, Asian
Development Bank, and
International Fund for
Agricultural Development. He has
worked in Tajikistan,
Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Uganda,
Kenya, and India. Dr. Patel has
published 3 books on optimal
farming practices, use of tools
in farming, and rural economics
and has contributed over 500
papers on these subjects. |
Table No.1
Productivity of
selected crops /ha and milk/ lactation
period in India and some other
countries
Country |
Paddy |
Wheat |
Maize |
Sugarcane |
Cotton |
Milk |
India |
2811 |
2559 |
1481 |
69197 |
922 |
1000 |
China |
6062 |
3759 |
5173 |
59589 |
2302 |
1476 |
Indonesia |
4515 |
|
2362 |
80133 |
|
|
USA |
6860 |
2442 |
7975 |
73816 |
2043 |
7454 |
Canada |
2558 |
2410 |
7255 |
|
|
6255 |
World |
3730 |
2541 |
4117 |
61304 |
1581 |
2305 |
Risks Associated with
Agricultural Lending
Profitability and Risks
of On-farm Lending
The major factors that affect
banker and farmer behavior in on-farm
lending operations are the expected
profitability of and the risks related
to on-farm investments. Risks can be
of different natures and include those
associated with the impact of
unfavorable weather on production
[drought, hail, floods etc] diseases
and pests damage, economic risks due
to uncertain markets and prices,
productivity and management risks
related to the adoption of new
technologies, and credit risks as they
depend on the utilization of financial
resources and the repayment behavior
of farmer clients. The relative
importance of these different risks
will vary by region and by type of
farmer. For example, marketing risks
are greater for mono-crop cultures and
under dry farming conditions. These
risks will decrease as the level of
education of farmers and availability
of information on markets, prices and
loan repayment behavior increase.
Additionally, agricultural insurance
may be useful as a risk management
tool, especially for relatively high
technology farming that involves
significant investment. This can be
used only for specific crop/livestock
enterprises and for clearly defined
risks.
Risks are also related to duration
of loans, since the uncertainty of
farm incomes and the probability of
losses increases over longer time
horizons. Thus, given the average
short maturity of loan-worthy
resources in deposit-taking financial
institutions, and considering the time
horizon of agricultural seasonal and
investment loans, commercial banks are
normally reluctant to engage
themselves in agricultural lending. To
protect themselves, banks should
carefully match the maturity of their
loans with that of their loan-worthy
resources and apply measures to
protect their loan portfolio from
potential risk losses.
Additional risk protection measures
that present added costs to borrowers
include insurance coverage against
insurable risks such as specified
adverse weather events leading to crop
damage or insurance against fire
[buildings and crops] and theft
[moveable assets] Government or donor
financed loan guarantee schemes, in
general, have not led to significantly
increased lending [additionally] and
they should be carefully designed in
order to secure appropriate risk
management and sharing as well
as cost effective administration. On
the other hand, mutual guarantee
associations have proven their
usefulness. Banks also control their
financial exposure by limiting their
loans to only a portion of the total
investment costs and by requiring that
the borrower engages sufficient equity
as well as careful diversification of
their loan portfolio in terms of
lending purposes, market segments and
loan maturities. Portfolio
diversification is a key to
sustainability and successful risk
management.
|
|
Institutional Risks
Financial institutions face four major
risks
-
Credit or loan
default risk refers to borrowers who
are unable or unwilling to repay the
loan principal and to service the
interest rate charges.
-
Liquidity risk-occurs
when a bank is not able to meet its
cash requirements. Mismatching the
term of loan assets and liabilities
[sources of loan-worthy funds]
exposes banks to high liquidity
risks.
-
Interest rate risk-
risk that a loan will decline in
value as interest rate change
-
Foreign exchange
risk- defines exposure to changes in
exchange rates which affect
international borrowings denominated
in foreign currency.
Risks impact borrowing farmers and the
financial institutions that lend to
them. Active management can reduce
these risks. Risks and uncertainty are
pervasive in agricultural production
and are perceived to be more serious
than in most non-farm activities.
Production losses are also extremely
difficult to predict. They can have
serious consequences for income
generation and for the loan repayment
capacity of the borrowing farmers. The
type and the severity of risks which
farmers face vary with the type of
farming system, the physical and
economic conditions, the prevailing
policies, etc.
Agricultural lending implies high
liquidity risks due to seasonality of
farm household income. Surpluses
supply increased savings capacity and
reduced demand for loans after harvest
and deficits reduce savings capacity
and increase demand for loans before
planting a crop. Also, agricultural
lenders face particular challenges
when many or all of their borrowers
are affected by external factors at
the same time. This condition is
referred to as covariant risk which
can seriously undermine the quality of
agricultural loan portfolio. As a
result, the provision of viable,
sustainable financial services and the
development of a strong rural
financial system are contingent on the
ability of financial institutions to
assess, quantify and appropriately
manage various types of risks.
|
|
Production and yield risks
Yield uncertainty due to natural
hazards refers to the unpredictable
impact of weather, pests and diseases,
and calamities of farm production.
Risks severely impact younger, less
well established, but more ambitious
farmers. Especially affected are those
who embark on faming activities that
may generate a high potential income
at the price of concentrated risks
such as in the case of high input
monoculture of maize. Subsequent loan
defaults may adversely affect the
credit worthiness of farmer borrowers
and their ability to secure future
loans.
Market and price risks
Price uncertainty due to market
fluctuations is particularly severe
where information is lacking and where
markets are imperfect, features that
are prevalent in the agricultural
sector in many developing countries.
The relatively long time period
between the decision to plant a crop
or to start a livestock enterprise and
the realization of farm output means
that market prices are unknown at the
moment when a loan is granted. This
problem is even more acute in tree
crops because of the gap of the
several years between planting and the
first harvest. These economic risks
have been particularly noticeable in
those countries where the former
single crop buyer was a parasitical
body. These organizations announced a
buying price before planting time.
Many disappeared following structural
adjustments reforms and privatization
of agricultural support services.
Private buyers rarely fix a
blanket-buying price prior to the
harvest, even though various
interlinked transactions for specific
crops have become more common today.
These arrangements almost always
involve the setting of a price or a
range of prices, prior to crop
planting.
Risk of loan collateral limitations
Problems associated with inadequate
loan collateral pose specific problems
to rural lenders. Land is the most
widely accepted asset for use as
collateral, because it is fixed and
not easily destroyed. It is often
prized by owners above its market
value and it has a high scarcity value
in densely populated area. Smallholder
farmers with land that has limited
value, or those who have only usufruct
rights, are less likely to have access
to bank loans. Moveable assets, such
as livestock and equipment are
regarded by lenders as higher risk
forms of security. The owner must
provide proof of purchase and have
insurance coverage on these items.
This is rarely the case for low-income
farm households.
|
|
Moreover, there are a number of loan
contract enforcement problems, even
when borrowers are able to meet the
loan collateral requirements.
Restrictions on the transfer of land
received through land reform programs
limits its value as collateral –even
when sound entitlement exists. In many
developing countries the poor and
especially women have most
difficulties in clearly demonstrating
their legal ownership of assets.
Innovative approaches which draw on
the practices of informal lenders and
provide incentives to low income
borrowers to pay back their loans have
been developed in micro-credit
programs.
Moral hazard risks in distorted credit
culture
Potentially serious risk problems are
showing up because of failed directed
credit programs. The impact on the
loan repayment discipline is
pervasive. Borrowers, who have
witnessed the emergence and demise of
lending institutions, have been
discouraged from repaying their loans.
Further people have repeatedly
received government funds under the
guise of “loansâ€. Loan clients have
been conditioned to expect
concessionary terms for institutional
credit.
Under these circumstances, the
incidence of moral hazard is high. The
local “credit culture†is distorted
among farmers and lenders. Borrowers
lack the discipline to meet their loan
repayment obligations, because loan
repayment commitments were not
enforced in the past. Lenders, on the
other hand, lack the systems,
experience and incentives to enforce
loan repayment. There is also an
urgent need to change bank staff
attitudes and the poor public image of
financial institutions in rural areas.
Another effect of distorted credit
culture on the risk exposure of
agricultural lenders is the priority
that borrowers give to repaying
strictly enforced informal loans.
These are settled before they comply
with the obligations associated with
“concessionary†institutional credit.
This is explained by the fact that
losing the access to informal credit
is viewed as more disadvantageous than
foregoing future bank loans [due to
the uncertain future of rural
financial institutions]. Very often
informal lenders have stronger
enforcement means than banks.
|
|
Risk from changes in
domestic and international policies
Policy changes and state interventions
can have a damaging impact on both
borrowers and lenders. For the latter
they can contribute significantly to
covariant risks. Many low-income
economies under the structural
adjustment program have slashed their
farming subsidies. This has had, for
instance, a serious effect on the
costs and the demand for fertilizer.
Reducing government expenditures as an
essential part of structural
adjustment programs may also affect
employment opportunities in the public
sector. Costs may even reduce
agricultural production levels, if
extension services are suddenly
discontinued.
While above risk factors have
significant impact on banks’ inability
to widen and deepen the credit
outreach more particularly in
dry-land. Drought prone, desert,
tribal and hilly areas following
policy issues have further created
adverse impact on banks to cover
small/marginal/ tenant farmers, oral
lessees, share croppers.
Directed
Credit
Since the early1950s government and
donors have spent large amounts on
agricultural credit programs in
developing countries. The World Bank
alone committed over US $ 16 billion
to these efforts from the mid-1950s to
the late 1980s and other donors also
spent substantial amounts. In several
countries such as Brazil, India,
Indonesia, Mexico and Sri Lanka,
supply-led and directed credit
programs were the dominant tools used
to spur agricultural development
during the three decades prior to the
1990s. In centrally planned countries
directed lending was likewise a
prominent instrument used to implement
agricultural production plans.
However, directed credit programs
still continue to play a strong role
in some developing countries viz.
Philippines, India etc.
The assumption behind these efforts
was that many farmers faced liquidity
constraints that limited their ability
to make farm investments and to use
additional modern inputs. Relaxing
these constraints by providing them
with loans, therefore, was thought to
be an easy way of stimulating farm
investments, boosting the use of
modern inputs and augmenting farm
production.
The proponents of the directed credit
approach assign many tasks to
financial markets on the one hand, but
on the other hand pay little attention
to providing and maintaining the
financial infrastructure needed to
carry out these assignments. In
contrast, the new market approach
assigns more modest role to financial
markets. The new approach stresses the
importance of the processes of
financial intermediation. The
principal goal in improving this
process is to enhance the efficiency
of resource allocation in the economy.
This is done by efficiently mobilizing
deposits from savers who otherwise,
have only low-return options for
investing their surplus funds, and
then efficiently allocating loans to
creditworthy borrowers who have too
few funds to capitalize on viable
investment opportunities.
|
|
The users of financial services in a
system strongly influenced by directed
credit tend to be borrowers rather
than depositors; the system is
borrower dominated. By contrast, the
new approach stresses the importance
of mobilizing local deposits, and
efficiently intermediating between
savers and borrowers. In India while
commercial and regional rural banks
mobilize savings, Primary Agricultural
Credit Societies are not allowed to
mobilize rural savings even from their
borrowers. Both commercial and
regional rural banks have yet not
developed saving mobilization
instruments/products best suited to
rural areas.
Typically, the volume of information
associated with directed credit
programs is substantial. Managers of
directed credit programs are able to
provide detailed information or data
required by funds providers, but are
unable to generate critical up-to-date
management information, such as the
status of loan recovery at any point
of time. While banks in India have to
collate, compile and furnish data
under agricultural credit programs in
the form of several returns
periodically, leaving practically very
little time for business development,
return on recovery of loans is annual
that does not provide status of
recovery/over due at any point of
time.
To justify subsidies associated with
directed credit programs, it is common
for credit planners to require that
credit impact studies be done on these
programs. These studies usually
require collection and analysis of
costly primary data that is not
ordinarily assembled by lenders. The
cost of managing the dense volume of
information generated by directed
credit activities typically augments
loan transaction costs for both lender
and borrower.
In contrast, the new approach
generates less but more useful data.
The absence of numerous directed
credit lines eliminates the need to
process data for each sub-program and
make staff available for development
of business including recovery
mobilization.
Since the new approach stresses making
loans based on creditworthiness of
borrowers and projects, rather than on
the basis of need, there is likewise
much less data processed on the
characteristics of borrowers and the
impact of these programs. The essence
of data collection and processing
under new approach is to manage
financial intermediaries efficiently
and prudently. The performance of
financial institution is measured by
indicators such as deposit
mobilization, transaction costs, loan
recovery, number of clients, and
financial and operational
sustainability.
|
|
The support for these traditional
directed agricultural credit efforts
began to wane in the 1980s and by the
end of the decade most donors and some
Governments sharply reduced their
support to agricultural credit. In
part, this decline in support was due
to the unsatisfactory performance of
these efforts. Critics increasingly
argued that relatively few of the
credit subsidies were captured by poor
people and that subsidized and
directed credit had a weak effect on
farm production and investment.
Serious and chronic loan recovery
problems, dependency on outside
funding, and overall costs eroded the
support for these efforts. Poor
performance and the lessening of donor
and Government support led to the
collapse of many public agricultural
development banks and [Government
directed] rural cooperatives in the
1980s. In some countries like Peru and
Bolivia traditional agricultural banks
were closed down. In other countries
such as The Gambia and ex-USSR all or
part of the development banks were
sold or privatized. Still in other
countries these development banks and
rural credit cooperatives persist but
their financing activities have been
sharply reduced, such as in Guatemala,
Nicaragua and Uganda. In India where
directed credit and Government
sponsored programs still persist,
commercial/cooperative banks and
regional rural banks face serious
problems of recovery of dues and had
to be re-capitalized whereas
co-operative banks are now being
considered for re-capitalization.
Subsidized Interest Rate
The proponents of directed credit
argue by justifying an interest rate
subsidy on loans for people because
they are poor, and justifying loan
waiver/write off because poor
borrowers later turned out to be “too
poor†to repay the loans.
Under the new approach there are no
subsidies associated with loans so
there are no favors associated with
lending. Financial intermediaries
treat their borrowers and depositors
as valued clients if they are to stay
in business. This forces
intermediaries to be attentive to the
quality of services they provide, to
the transaction costs they impose on
their clients and to financial
innovations that reduce these costs.
It was further assumed that most
farmers were too poor to save, that
informal financial markets were
dominated by monopolist money lenders
who charged usurious interest rates,
and that commercial banks were too
conservative to lend to most farmers.
Based on these assumptions Governments
and donors developed and funded
numerous directed credit programs
around the world. Most of these
efforts were heavily subsidized by
charging reduced interest rates or
tolerating loan defaults.
A common arrangement for providing
rural financial markets with donor or
Government funds was to open reduced
rediscount windows in the country’s
central banks to disburse funds to
selected groups, regions or
activities. Banks and other financial
institutions were stimulated to grant
targeted lending by making cheaper
debt funds available from the
rediscount window. The interest rates
on these funds were typically lower
than the rates lenders were paying for
alternative sources of funds. In the
later, 1970s, for example, the central
bank in Indonesia administered nearly
200 directed credit lines, many of
which were aimed at agricultural
activities, and most of which were
subsidized. In India National Bank has
been providing refinance at lowered
interest rate to the banking system
for farm and non-farm sector
development. In fact, National Bank’s
financial resources need to be
deployed directly for long term
investment purpose in developing
irrigation potential, horticultural
and plantation projects, establishing
agro-processing units, cold chains,
markets etc.
|
|
In some cases, the availability of
rediscount funds was augmented by
imposing loan portfolio requirements
on commercial banks, as for example in
India stipulated agricultural lending
at 18% of net bank credit and un-lent
portion to be lent for Rural
Infrastructure Development Fund at a
lower rate of interest to National
Bank. These requirements were intended
to compel banks to either make more
loans for purposes targeted by
Government, or to lend on more benign
terms to other institutions,
especially agricultural development
banks that were doing targeted
lending. In Thailand, for example,
during the 1970s and 1980s the
Government required all banks to lend
an increasing percentage of their
total loan portfolio to farmers. If
they were unable to comply directly
with this requirement, they were
allowed to fulfill their obligation by
lending money at discounted interest
rates to the Bank for Agriculture and
Agricultural Cooperatives. In some
countries subsidized loan guarantee
schemes were also established to
further encourage agricultural
lending, as for example in India
Deposit Insurance and Credit Guarantee
Scheme was established in early 1970s.
The assumption behind these schemes
was that by transferring part or all
of the loan recovery risk to the
insurance program, lenders would be
induced to do more of the lending
preferred by policy makers.
These subsidies take the form of
discounted lower interest rate on
funds provided to lenders, subsidized
interest rates on loans made to
beneficiaries, implicit subsidies
involved in loans that are not repaid
and written off, Government or donor
grants to cover costs of institution
involved in directed credit, and
subsidies for supporting loan
guarantee schemes.
An important objective of new approach
is to eliminate subsidies in rural
finance. Form of subsidies, if any,
should be temporary and transparent
and not linked to the lending
activities but rather to institution
building. To help reduce transaction
costs, for example, training of bank
staff in new lending practices or for
banking operations and automation may
be subsidized.
Since financial institutions are not
processing subsidies under the new
approach, they are much less
susceptible to rent seeking and
corruption, common features of the
directed credit approach.
As part of this process, many
countries formed or expanded
agricultural development banks to
handle the bulk of the targeted
lending. In many countries political
considerations were involved in loan
approval and recovery decisions.
Government mandated loan forgiveness
in Bangladesh and Loan Mela and loan
write-offs in India during 1980s being
examples of such political
interventions in financial sector
operations.
|
|
Shifts in political priorities and
donor preferences have often resulted
in substantial changes in roles
assigned to rural financial markets.
Sometimes farm production and farm
investments were stressed, while at
other times poverty alleviation,
pacifying the countryside, or disaster
relief were the primary objectives of
directed credit efforts, as for
example in India provision of targeted
and sub-targeted credit under the
Integrated Rural Development Program
focusing on direct attack on rural
poverty from 1978 and provision of
credit on soft terms to existing
borrowers when natural calamities
visit them in certain geographical
areas.
Conclusion
While our research institutions must
focus their attention to evolve
technology to mitigate risks, it is
high time that India must develop
sustainable Agricultural Insurance
Scheme and related insurance products
that can help farmers significantly
minimize incidence of income loss.
Besides, State Governments must
concentrate on creating infrastructure
that can sustain agricultural
development. The Reserve Bank of India
should develop incentives for
commercial banks to lend to the
agricultural sector and mobilize rural
savings.
|
|
|